![Image of Lake Powell](/sites/default/files/styles/full_width_1024px_5_3_/public/2024-08/Lake%20Powell%205x3.jpg?itok=LdtPIPXF)
![Image of Lake Powell](/sites/default/files/styles/full_width_1024px_5_3_/public/2024-08/Lake%20Powell%205x3.jpg?itok=LdtPIPXF)
Insights from
Written by
Research by Darden Professor Samuel E. Bodily suggests several new ways to encourage entrepreneurs teetering on the edge of launching a high potential startup but fearful of the financial risks involved.
“You want to support entrepreneurs with good ideas who are aware of the risks and want to mitigate them,” says Bodily. “You want to motivate socially minded entrepreneurs to persevere in their quest to take on the world’s most pressing challenges.”
So how best to do it?
“Let us consider some innovation in funding to match the innovation inherent in entrepreneurship,” Bodily writes in his article titled “Reducing Risk and Improving Incentives in Funding Entrepreneurs,” published in the June 2016 issue of the journal Decision Analysis. His research proposes novel methods on how “to nudge an entrepreneur over the risk barrier and down the startup path.”
Bodily uses a classic example of a risk gone bad to illustrate the dilemma faced by stakeholders who want to invest in a worthy entrepreneurial cause. Over the past decade, backers — including the federal government, foundations, individuals and others — invested more than $100 billion in promising early-stage clean-tech companies such as KiOR, Solyndra and Ener1. They hoped the innovative companies would find original ways to reduce global energy consumption and improve the world.
Instead, the companies went bankrupt as the cost of petroleum plummeted, making innovative alternative energy too costly by comparison.
“But, if we assume that it is appropriate to encourage clean-tech entrepreneurs to pursue potentially revolutionary new ideas, could we do so more effectively?” asks Bodily. “Are there better ways for backers to encourage startups by reducing risk more efficiently than was done in the past?”
Also, backers should keep in mind the psychological needs of these risk-averse entrepreneurs, Bodily says. An entrepreneur may see the startup as his or her child “with all the desire for control over its destiny that parenthood might entail.” And entrepreneurs may have all their financial resources on the line. They need risk sharing, he asserts.
Using decision analysis, Bodily formulated a model with changeable parameters “related to the business itself, the risk tolerance of the entrepreneur and the cost of subsidy of the mechanisms” to look at tried and true financial mechanisms including equity participation, outright incentive gifts and insurance against loss. He also looked at two new ideas: revenue contracts and swap hedges.
Bodily’s model — using a certainty equivalent (a risk-adjusted measure that represents the precise certain amount that the entrepreneur would trade for an uncertain payout) — found that two other financial tools might prove the most helpful to the risk-averse entrepreneur.
For example, the objective index for a clean-tech startup could be a petroleum price index; for a new online retailer venture, it might be the Russell Business Cycle Index, which forecasts the strength and direction of the business cycle; or for a real estate business startup, it might be the Case-Shiller Home Price Indices, which track changes in the value of residential real estate.
“There is another strong reason to favor the swap hedge. Because the swap contract is written on the outcome of an objective index, the entrepreneur has no incentive to be complacent or to give up, whether the index turns out to be favorable or unfavorable,” Bodily says.
“If entrepreneurs end up succeeding even when the index is unfavorable, they get to keep the entire reward of their efforts, including the positive payout of the swap,” says Bodily. “They will always strive to do the very best they can.” And the risk to the backer is related to the index, not to the entrepreneur’s effort. Consequently, there is no moral hazard.
“In short, the swap hedge is a lot more efficient way of reducing risk while offering less moral hazard and encouraging innovation,” says Bodily.
The preceding features research detailed in “Reducing Risk and Improving Incentives in Funding Entrepreneurs,” by Samuel E. Bodily, Decision Analysis, Vol. 13, No. 2, June 2016, pp. 101-116.
Professor Bodily further discusses his findings in the Batten Briefing Consider the Alternatives: New Ways of Financing Early-Stage Entrepreneurs, as well as Research & Relevance: New Ways of Financing Early Stage Entrepreneurs, a podcast produced by Darden’s Batten Institute for Entrepreneurship and Innovation. Professor Bodily, a Batten Fellow, is interviewed by Erika Herz (MBA ’01), Batten’s director of research and intellectual capital.
How do people weigh risks, then make decisions? Bodily is an expert on decision and risk analysis, publishing in journals ranging from Operations Research to Harvard Business Review. In 2012, he co-authored the paper “Multiplicative Utilities for Health and Consumption,” receiving the best paper award in the journal Decision Analysis.
Bodily is also an expert in strategy modeling and analysis, lifetime consumption and investment planning. He focuses on energy and electric utility industries, forecasting methods, probability and statistics, and revenue management. He is a consultant to many corporations, utilities and government agencies.
B.S., Brigham Young University; S.M., Ph.D., Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Nudging the Entrepreneur Down the Startup Path
Share